11
BIG TECHS, DATA
PROTECTION, AND
COMPETITION REGULATION
IN A DATA-DRIVEN ECONOMY:
A MULTIDISCIPLINARY
APPROACH
1
Big Techs, Proteção de Dados e Regulação de
Concorrência em uma Economia Baseada em
Dados: uma abordagem multidisciplinar
Amanda de Castro Cavallaro
2
Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul (UFRGS) – Porto Alegre/RS, Brasil
STRUCTURED ABSTRACT
Context: The rapid growth of the Information Economy and the consolidation of the Big Tech
Monopoly in Digital Markets have made privacy and data protection a central concern for consumers
and regulatory authorities worldwide. The increasing relevance of personal data as both a market
asset and a fundamental right has highlighted the need for new regulatory approaches to address
these issues.
Objective: This article aims to explore how competition regulation can be used as a mechanism to
protect privacy and data protection in the digital markets.
Method: The research employs a qualitative approach through a critical analysis of relevant literature,
including legal documents and reports from regulatory authorities. The analysis is conducted through
a perspective that integrates competition regulation and privacy and data protection matters.
In addition, its theoretical references are Shoshana Zubo and Evgeny Morozov, besides other
instruments of national and international regulatory law.
Conclusions: The study concludes that competition regulation can play a vital role in protecting
privacy and data protection in the digital markets. By promoting competition and preventing anti-
competitive behavior by dominant players, competition law can help to create an environment
where privacy and data protection are prioritized by companies. Additionally, competition policy can
Editor responsável: Prof. Dr. Luis Henrique Bertolino Braido, Fundação Getúlio Vargas (FGV/RJ), Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brasil.
Lattes: http://lattes.cnpq.br/4648392251476133. ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-6085-1446.
1 Recebido em: 09/07/2023 Aceito em: 06/11/2023 Publicado em: 21/12/2023
2 Mestranda em Direito Europeu e Alemão no Programa de Pós-Graduação em Direito da Universidade Federal do Rio
Grande do Sul (PPGD-UFRGS), em cooperação com o Centro de Estudos Europeus e Alemães (Zentrum für Deutschland und
Europastudien). Pós-graduanda em Direito Empresarial na Pontifícia Universidade Católica do Rio Grande do Sul (PUCRS).
Bacharela em Ciências Jurídicas e Sociais na Universidade Federal da Paraíba (UFPB). Advogada e Coordenadora do núcleo
de Privacidade e Proteção de Dados do Martinelli & Guimarães Advocacia. Mentoranda do Women in Law Mentoring (WLM).
Membro da Diretoria de Articulação do WiCADE (WIA-CADE). E-mail: cavallaro.amandac@gmail.com
Lattes: http://lattes.cnpq.br/7666625008508878 ORCID: https://orcid.org/0009-0007-6913-2561
1
12
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
complement data protection regulation by providing an additional layer of protection for consumers.
Keywords: competition regulation; digital markets; Big Tech; monopoly; privacy; data protection.
RESUMO ESTRUTURADO
Contexto: O rápido crescimento da Economia da Informação e a consolidação do monopólio das Big
Techs nos Mercados Digitais tornaram a privacidade e a proteção de dados uma preocupação central
dos consumidores e das autoridades reguladoras em todo o mundo. A crescente relevância dos
dados pessoais como um ativo de mercado e um direito fundamental tem destacado a necessidade
de novas abordagens regulatórias para tratar destas questões.
Objetivo: Este artigo tem como objetivo explorar como a regulação da concorrência pode ser utilizada
como um mecanismo para proteger a privacidade e a proteção de dados nos mercados digitais.
Método: A pesquisa emprega uma abordagem qualitativa por meio de uma análise crítica da
literatura relevante, incluindo documentos legais e relatórios de autoridades reguladoras. A análise
é conduzida a partir de uma perspectiva que integra a regulação da concorrência e a matéria de
privacidade proteção de dados. Além disso, possui como referências teóricos a Soshana Zubo e o
Evgeny Morozov, para além das demais normas do direito regulatório nacional e internacional.
Conclusões: O estudo conclui que a regulação da concorrência pode desempenhar um papel vital na
proteção da privacidade e da proteção de dados nos mercados digitais. Ao promover a concorrência
e impedir comportamentos anticompetitivos por jogadores dominantes, a lei da concorrência
pode ajudar a criar um ambiente onde a privacidade e a proteção de dados são priorizadas pelas
empresas. Além disso, a política de concorrência pode complementar a regulação da proteção de
dados, fornecendo uma camada adicional de proteção para os consumidores.
Palavras-chave: regulação da concorrência; mercados digitais; Big Tech; monopólio; privacidade;
proteção de dados;
Classicação JEL: K21; K24; L12; O33.
Summary: 1. Introduction; 2. Informational Economy,
Digital Markets and Privacy; 3. Big Techs Monopoly,
behavioral proling and instrumentarian power”; 4.
Competition Regulation in the Informational Economy;
Conclusion; References.
1. INTRODUCTION
The beginning of the 21st century is marked by a series of events and social, political, economic
changes, in addition to an exponential technological development that has revolutionized the world and
the way individuals interact with it. In this context, it is possible to state that technological development
has been driven by profit, and has even been one of the pillars of the history of technology itself. Thus,
as technology evolved, the economic relations that involved it also prospered, just as society molded
itself in this new paradigm of what we have come to call the “Information Age.
From this perspective, data began to play a key role in economic relations, while surveillance
13
became the foundational mechanism of this new form of market. The abrupt rise of the Silicon
Valley giants implied a series of consequences – social, economic, political – and, among them, the
weakening of privacy and data protection, which is the focus of this paper.
In June 2019, the United States House of Representatives began investigating the actual
parameters of competition from tech giants, in particular, the market domination exercised by Big
Techs. The intention was to determine the power wielded by the giants, such as the consequences of
economic domination and threats to American democracy. Nevertheless, the subcommittee analyzed
the existing antitrust laws, such as competition policies and their eciency as a way to check how
adequate they are to manage the digital market power and its competition conducts. For example,
each platform acts as a gatekeeper over a key distribution channel, as it is possible to observe, for
example, Meta (formerly Facebook), which holds evident domination over communication platforms,
since it alone owns Facebook, Messenger, Instagram, WhatsApp. In this sense, by controlling access
to markets, the technological giants have the power to choose the winners and losers throughout
our economy.
The report revealed that each platform uses its gatekeeper position to maintain its market
power to control the infrastructure of the digital age by acquiring other companies – potential rivals – in
order to cut down on their competitive threats. In this sense, Mark Zuckerberg himself, when speaking
on the subject, did not deny that he saw Instagram as a threat, which motivated the acquisition of the
application in 2012, for the amount of one billion dollars, such an event caused a real shock in market
economists, considering that at the time Instagram was a company with only 13 employees.
The lack of real competitiveness has led the technology giants to establish a low standard of
data protection and privacy protection. In this conjuncture, even though privacy and personal data
have received the status of fundamental rights of individuals, enshrined in constitutions such as the
Brazilian Federal Constitution and in international treaties such as the Universal Declaration of Human
Rights, tech companies still maintain a predatory posture towards personal information of users.
The rise of the Informational Economy and the dominance of Big Tech companies in digital
markets have brought privacy and data protection to the forefront of consumer and regulatory
concerns. The increasing relevance of personal data as both a market asset and a fundamental right
has highlighted the need for new regulatory approaches to address these issues. This article aims
to explore how competition regulation can be used as a mechanism to protect privacy and data
protection in the digital markets, with a multidisciplinary approach that integrates legal, economic,
and technological perspectives.
For its purpose, this article is divided into three main parts. Firstly, it discusses the
transformation of the economy with the rise of digital technologies, characterized by the increasing
importance of data as a strategic asset, and the emergence of digital markets dominated by Big
Tech companies. Continually, the second topic, addresses the intersection between competition
and data privacy concerns, focusing on the practice of behavioral profiling and the potential for
“instrumentarian power”. At last, the article explores the potential role of competition regulation
in protecting privacy and data protection in the digital markets, with a particular emphasis on the
Digital Markets Act (DMA) proposed by the European Commission.
By examining the intricate connection between competition regulation and privacy and data
protection, this article oers an overview of the challenges and opportunities of creating a more
14
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
sustainable and equitable digital economy. By all means, it elucidates the way in which Big Techs
companies leverage their power to consolidate their dominance, especially when they exploit their
role as intermediaries to strengthen and extend their control. This way, by adopting a multidisciplinary
approach that considers legal, economic, and technological factors, this article aims to highlight
the importance of policymakers and stakeholders cultivating an eective solution that balances the
benefits of digital innovation with the need to protect fundamental rights and values in the digital
age, as the competition regulation in the digital markets, that, although cannot guarantee absolute
privacy and data protection, it is indispensable for curbing the hegemony of large technology
corporations and promoting healthy competition.
2. INFORMATIONAL ECONOMY, DIGITAL MARKETS AND PRIVACY
It is important to note that the rise of Big Techs – understood as large technology companies
associated with platforms for intensive use and exploitation of data (MOROZOV, 2018, p. 144) –
happened at a minimally curious historical juncture. Following the global financial crisis of 2008, an
unfavorable scenario overlapped by the Silicon Valley giants, and as the economy began to recover,
Big Techs found a fertile ground for significant, unbridled and, above all, unnoticed growth, this being
one of the temporal milestones that favored their accelerated growth.
Ater 2008, the globe was facing the biggest economic disaster since 1929, scenario that the
Big Techs appeared as true “saviors” of the economy. The rise of tech giants succeeded in part because
they helped in coping with the crisis, since they provided institutions or citizens with the ability to
supplement their budgets and revenues through new sources of income, as well as enabling a radical
reduction in costs (MOROZOV, 2018, p. 144). Similarly, over 10 years later, the Covid-19 health crisis
boosted the increasingly widespread digitalization of various aspects of human life, since lockdowns
and remote working have enlarged demands for a rang of big tech’s oerings (KSHETRI, 2020, p. 10).
Notwithstanding the social role that Big Techs played, the expansion of these companies
also sustain a smooth transition to a new economic model, which would come to be known as
the information economy. It is important to note that, in general, privacy tends to be renegade
before values involving national security, terrorism, eciency, or entrepreneurship (DIAS, 2017, p.
172). Which is precisely the combination of circumstances observed in that conjuncture, favoring the
rise of the tech giants.
As it was, the rise of Big Techs is not – and should not be – understood as a symptom of
the great global financial crisis, instead, it appears as a solution amidst the tribulation of the time,
and very ambitiously, as a promise of a new economic and political commitment, a New Deal 2.0
(MOROZOV, 2018, p. 145). Thus, while the giants presented themselves as a way out of the crisis, the
Big Techs gauged one of the facilitators that enabled their exponential and indiscriminate growth.
By all means, it is important to note that technological innovations were still exciting for users at
that moment, so the idea of personal technology use as a device that could cause harm was only
an academic debate, which was not taken seriously by popular culture, instead, the possibility of a
media that was accessible to the entire population was considered a democratizing force. It was not
expected, however, that the strengthening of the technology giants, as it happened, would turn into
a democratic threat, as can be seen today.
15
Under the premise of national security and the fight against terrorism, the loosening of the
right to individual privacy has been increasingly perceived, leading to surveillance practices. This
phenomenon can be observed since surveillance has become increasingly present, made possible by
the expansion at a frenetic pace of permissive legislation to collect data.
In this sense, Google, considered as the pioneer of this new economic model, also benefited
from the premise of national security, inflated by the events of the time, especially the September
11 attacks. The government itself was inclined to support, emulate, safeguard, and take ownership
of the emerging capabilities of surveillance capitalism in the name of complete knowledge and the
assurance of absolute certainty (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 24).
Although data protection legislation dates back to the mid-twentieth century, such as the
Hessian Law of 1970, in Germany, a distinct trend towards more restrictive and invasive surveillance
practices was observed, resulting from the abrupt change of focus of the public power and government
policies ater the attack on the twin towers in 2001 (LYON, 2003, p. 7). Thus, Big Techs, as creators and
owners of technology – and guardians of citizens' data – unequivocally were already ahead in the
development of surveillance mechanisms, to the extent that the fight against terrorism on behalf of
national security, by sotening the guidelines of data protection and privacy, contributed to the rise
of Silicon Valley companies.
Meanwhile, a new social model was being organized in which information is the core element
of economic development, so as to be the pillar around which society reorganizes and restructures
itself. With technological development occurring at an increasingly accelerated level at all times,
all kinds of information have become digitized. The exponential valorization of digital companies
relies on the fact that they have control over the most important resource of the 21st century: data.
Therefore, the key premise of data extractivism is that users are stocks of valuable information
together with the fact that we “voluntarily” give up our information in exchange for enjoying the
technology oered (MOROZOV, 2018, p. 165).
Against the background of the information economy, based on data extraction, the
informational flow prevails over any other means of production as the determining resource in the
economic cycle (BIONI, 2019, p. 10). Such that, from the moment that information becomes an asset,
inevitably new market mechanisms will arise with the intention of exploiting the information, and
transform it into a product. For example, there is the so-called zero-price advertisement business
model, in which users do not directly pay a monetary amount for the product or service, however, in
return, they provide their personal information (BIONI, 2019, p. 49).
Therefore, data is now used as an exchange currency, so without the provision of information
the user will not be able to enjoy the product or service. Thus, the citizen is let with only two
options: surrender his personal information or be excluded from the digital media – which make up
a considerable part of social interactions. It is worth noting that despite the fact that data by itself
already has considerable value, information is not in itself what leverages eciency in business
activity, but its processing-organization to be transformed into applied knowledge. In this way,
the creation of the so-called behavioral profile of the user is observed, composed of traits of the
individual's personality, based on the extraction of his personal data.
By the end of the 2000s, Google decided to abandon the reciprocal relationship it had with its
users – which until then collected and recycled data in order to create a profile that brought satisfactory
16
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
results to customers – and started using its own arsenal of behavioral data, along with its computing
power and expertise, with the sole task of matching advertisements with users' searches, with this data
are transformed into marketable knowledge (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 75). Therefore, from the possibility of
reorganizing data and structuring them in a scalable way – especially with the development of Big Data
– the development of a new market supported by the extractivism of data and its “commodification”
was observed (BIONI, 2019, p. 13). Thus, the capitalism of surveillance arises, in which the citizen loses
autonomy over his information, positioning himself as a mere spectator of his data.
It is in this particular context that surveillance capitalism has emerged as a novel market
phenomenon that operates on a distinctive logic of accumulation. It relies heavily on surveillance as
a foundational mechanism to convert investment into profit, with privacy being the cost of accessing
the abundant rewards of digital goods, information, and connectivity that consumers demand. The
market structure that underpins the informational economy is known as surveillance capitalism.
Not only was the economic crisis a considerable fertile ground, but the technology giants
also counted on the American anti-terrorist fight frenzy, especially ater the events of September 11,
which led to the devaluation of the right to individual privacy in favor of surveillance and national
security (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 112). This is another factor that made it possible for data to be collected on
a massive scale. As a result, the formation of an informational economy based on the extraction of
data was observed.
Furthermore, the establishment of a new dominant economy in the market, the informational
economy, which has as its epicenter the data, provided by users itself. In this scenario, data has
become the most valuable asset of contemporaneity, having even surpassed oil in market value (THE
GREAT... 2019). Although the information collected by technology companies alone had enormous
economic value, it is worth noting that when cross-referenced, it became capable of creating a
behavioral profile of each user (NYBO, 2019, p. 146).
In this matter, the Facebook-Cambridge Analytica case is considered a major watershed
regarding discussions of data analysis for behavioral profiling and its use for economic, political, and
individual personality manipulation. In the words of Christopher Wylie – former research director of
Cambridge Analytica – the company was characterized as a military and psychological manipulation
contractor for information warfare, which comprised a complex web involving Facebook, Russia,
WikiLeaks, the Trump campaign, and the Brexit referendum (WYLIE, 2019, p. 9).
As Brittany Kaiser points out in the documentary “The Great Hack”, Cambridge Analytica had full
knowledge that their targeting tool was considered a weapon, and they used it anyway to manipulate
and make the world be seen through their lens (THE GREAT…, 2019). In a way that “new automated
protocols are designed to influence and modify human behavior at scale as the means of production
is subordinated to a new and more complex means of behavior modification” (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 25).
Hence, Cambridge Analytica used aspects of users' individual personality – by illegitimately
collecting information through the user's Facebook profile and friends – to shape a voter profile
of each user. Based on this engineering, they were able to identify those they considered to be
“influenceable”, whom would be targeted with oriented advertising, in order to shape how they saw
the world and thus entice their behavior in the 2016 election (THE GREAT…, 2019). In this regard, the
electoral operation prepared by Cambridge was essentially responsible for the unexpected victory of
Trump, who took advantage of this engineering of personal data to mobilize electoral public opinion,
17
especially of those most susceptible to convincing, through the dissemination of fake news.
Thus, it is observed that the Cambridge Analytica controversy was an event that revolutionized
the discussions about the way Big Techs manage users’ personal information. On point, it is worth
noting that the event highlighted the risks that the monopoly of technology giants can bring to
the rights of individuals, in their intimate sphere and in relation to their dignity. In addition to
demonstrating the economic and political power that these private companies wield; they also
represent a threat to democracy.
Although this development was originally aimed at creating targeted marketing, the creation
of a behavioral profile had several reflections on the personal life of the holder of the information,
aecting much more than their purchasing pattern, but their interpersonal relationships and their
psyches. Therefore, it is clear that Big Techs have relied on several factors, social and economic, in
addition to technological development itself for their growth. In this sense, “technology is not and
never can be a thing in itself isolated from the economy and society” (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 21). Thus, the
rise of the technological giants of Silicon Valley is grounded by the historical milestones that favored
its exponential development.
The role of information as a means of optimizing economic development predates even the
creation of the internet. However, it was due to technological changes that it was possible to glimpse
a series of economic, social and cultural changes, which made possible an environment of radical
transformation (BENKLER, 2006, p. 1), and is perceived as the “Internet Revolution” since “Internet is,
above all, a cultural creation” (CASTELLS, 2001, p. 7).
Therefore, the creation of the “Informational Economy” is observed and understood as a
phenomenon that operates as a kind of electronic nervous system in which information and personal
data start to have a predominant role over the means of production (BIONI, 2019, p. 11). Thus, it is
glimpsed that the change brought about by digital media is profound and structural, starting from
the very foundations of how markets and liberal democracies have developed over the last two
centuries (BENKLER, 2006, p. 1).
3. BIG TECHS MONOPOLY, BEHAVIORAL PROFILING AND “INSTRUMENTARIAN
POWER”
Although monopoly is a culturally unacceptable practice – in which companies carried with
them the virtue of competition – the technological giants barged in the market carrying not only
technological innovations, but the longing for monopoly. Within this context, we witness a rupture
of the traditional American market's virtues, as the Big Techs of the Silicon Valley perceive their
concentration of power as a critical social asset, believing that it is the key to achieving global
harmony and undoing the alienation of humanity (FOER, 2017, p. 18).
In the digital age, the global economy is increasingly characterized by data-driven processes
that harness personal of data at their disposal to shape our online experiences and, by extension,
our real-world behaviors, “instrumentarian power”, in a way that Big Tech companies occupy a central
role at the intersection of competition and data privacy.
In light of this, the US House of Representatives not only produced sucient evidence of the
18
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
dominance exercised by Silicon Valley giants, but also observed that these companies control the
market in their respective sectors while competing only with each other. This position allows Big Techs
to dictate rules to other companies while maintaining a power game within their own regulations (US
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 2). In this regard, Morozov (2018, p. 146) asserts that the rapid
rise of digital platforms has produced a parallel, virtually invisible, privatized welfare state.
Regarding Big Techs, it is understood that the control of a platform over data not only
consolidates its dominant position – as it allows platforms to adapt their services according to demand
– but also confers an advantage over other lines of business (KHAN, 2016, p. 785). Furthermore, the
Brazilian antitrust authority, Conselho Administrativo de Defesa da Concorrência (Cade), in its working
document on competition in digital markets, concluded that Big Techs possess all the characteristics
that consolidate their market power, enabling them to earn economic rents without facing threats
from new competitors. Not only, it was possible to verify that the entry of new competitors into
markets already dominated by Silicon Valley giants has been extremely dicult, allowing them to
charge high prices, reduce product quality, and invest less in innovation without the risk of losing
consumers (LANCIERI; SAKOWSKI, 2020, p. 34).
Additionally, the Silicon Valley giants, as dominant platforms, have in many cases also
integrated into adjacent businesses in such a way as to act as key intermediaries for both third-
party companies, typically smaller ones, and their direct competitors. In this context, based on the
compilation of numerous significant reports by the US House of Representatives, it was not only
possible to identify but also to document the monopoly power exercised by the Silicon Valley giants
and how these dominant platforms can exploit this dual intermediary role through data exploitation,
self-preferencing, appropriation of key technologies, and abrupt changes in platform policies (US
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 30).
Under this matter, and parting from another perspective, while each Big Tech acts as a
monopolist in its respective field, it’s conceivable to argue that their overall market behavior might
appear inconsistent with that of a monopoly, suggesting the existence of some form of oligopoly among
the technology giants as a whole. From this perspective, an “alternative concept for characterizing the
state of large-scale technological competition as that of ‘moligopoly’” (PETIT, 2020, p. 153) arises, in
which Big Techs compete against each other, or on a smaller scale, against smaller companies.
Despite these noteworthy outlined inconsistencies, it would still be unreasonable to disregard
the power exercised by Big Techs, in the process of its characterization as a monopoly. As a matter of
fact “even if a company does not operate alone in the market, it may still hold such (i.e. significant)
economic power that it can act independently and with indierence to the presence or performance
of other players (FORGIONI, 2022, p. 268). As long as Big Techs control key distribution channels and
act as gatekeepers, a large swath of businesses across the US economy – and the world – will remain
dependent on them to access users and markets.
At last, the monopolies of Big Techs are characterized by various instances of power that
go beyond the realm of economics and into social and political aspects as well. To the point, the
issue with the techno-utopian stories propagated by Silicon Valley is that they tend to overlook the
full extent of the current crisis and fail to acknowledge the impact of their own agendas on their
social and political rhetoric (MOROZOV, 2018, p. 162). As a consequence, this lack of transparency
regarding their intentions and motives undermines the credibility of their narratives and hinders
19
the development of more nuanced and eective solutions to the challenges posed by technology
in society. Therefore, the dominance exerted by technology giants, both in economic and social-
political aspects, is sucient to characterize their monopolies.
The high costs and large network eects constitutes real barriers to the entry of new players
in the digital markets already dominated by the tech giants, in face of the enormous diculty to
oer goods or services on a competitive level or even enter the market (KOURY; OLIVEIRA, 2022, p.
97). Subsequently, the Cade concluded that Big Techs hold all the characteristics that consolidate
their market power, so as to allow them to earn economic profits without being threatened by new
competitors. In addition, it was possible to verify that the technological giants to have the power to
charge high prices, lower the quality of their products and invest less in innovation without the risk
of losing consumers (LANCIERI; SAKOWSKI 2020, p. 34).
Also, it is worth noting that the Silicon Valley giants, as dominant platforms, have in many
cases also integrated themselves into adjacent businesses in such a way as to act as key intermediaries
for both usually smaller third-party companies and their direct competitors and how these dominant
platforms can exploit this dual role as intermediaries, through data mining, self-preferring appropriation
of key technologies, and abrupt changes in a platform's policies. Not only that, “dominant platforms
exploit this gatekeeper power to dictate terms and extract concessions that third parties would not
consent to in a competitive market” (US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 29).
Understanding the way in which Big Techs have instrumentalized such power is essential
to realizing the extent of the impacts resulting from their market dominance. As data controllers,
digital platforms have the option to make use of personal information in ways that are more or less
beneficial to users. So while tech giants can use data to improve oerings and make service faster
and more individualized, they also have the power to simply collect and store data for its value or
competitive advantage (SHELANSKI, 2013, p. 1689). The monopoly of technology giants represents
more than an economic threat, it represents a threat to democracy as we know, and as Big Techs
consolidate their monopoly and acquire even more power, the bigger they get, including parallelly to
the Govern State.
On point, there is no doubt that Big Techs can either choose to establish strict security and
privacy standards to protect users' data, or to deprioritize data protection and so use the personal
information for their own benefit and against the interests of the data owners. Therefore, since
the technology giants have the power to determine how they will dispose of individuals' personal
information – regardless of how damaging it is to the privacy of the users – and still succeed in
keeping them as consumers, this feature is proof of the power and market dominance of platforms
in the digital economy.
In this matter, taking as a historically premise that the ability to control information has
been a fundamental factor in shaping the distribution of power within societies (DONEDA, 2020, p.
34), it is observed that the way in which companies carry out the extractive operations of user data,
starting from a qualitative perspective, represents a direct expression of their monopolistic power
(SRINIVASAN, 2019, p. 44). As such, a company's dominance over a certain digital market segment
allows it to abuse consumers' privacy without losing customers – if they do not wish to renounce
the service in its entirety, as they have no choice but to submit to fragile data protection standards
– highlights that every single promise made by Big Techs is made so that we can only enjoy it to the
20
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
fullest if we surrender completely and give up our privacy (MOROZOV, 1984, p. 171).
Continuously, it is worth noting that “the fact that the product is free falsely diverts attention
from what antitrust policymakers and economists are most comfortable paying attention to: price”
(SRINIVASAN, 2019, p. 44). However, it should be kept in mind that “a platform’s ability to maintain strong
networks while degrading user privacy can reasonably be considered equivalent to a monopolist’s
decision to raise prices or reduce product quality” (US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 40). In
the absence of genuine competitive threats, the dominant company oers fewer privacy protections
than it would otherwise, with the aim to extract more data, and further consolidate its dominance.
Nevertheless, the Silicon Valley giants use abusive practices – by exploiting their role as
intermediaries – in order to strengthen and expand even more their dominance. Whether through
self-preference, predatory pricing, or exclusionary conduct, Big Techs have exploited their power in
an eort to become even more dominant, making it impossible for potential competitors to emerge
and develop that could challenge their dominance. Therefore, the monopolization of public markets
can lead to the establishment of a “private government”, controlled by a small group of people who
hold the monopoly, as corporations, once merely an ecient tool employed by individuals to conduct
private business, have become an institution that has brought such a concentration of economic
power capable of dominating the State (U. S. SUPREME COURT, 1933).
As the surveillance capitalism, the market-oriented structure of the digital economy, behaves
as “a coup from above, not an overthrow of the state but an overthrow of the people’s sovereignty and
a prominent force” (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 33) in the dangerous trend toward democratic deconsolidation.
Hence, the technology giants have managed to develop a digital apparatus by which they impose
their will, and exert their influence through a tangible, computational, interconnected puppet that
observes, calculates, and alters human conduct. They use this infrastructure to establish a method
of characterizing and – specially – modifying behavior, which it is called “instrumentarian power”,
replacing the traditional practice of soul engineering with behavior engineering.
In this context, the instrumentarian power aims at organizing, enticing, and tuning the whole
social body in order to obtain some kind of social confluence that replaces the role of politics and
democracy with group pressure and computational certainty, resulting in the extinguishment of our
perception of reality and the purpose of individual social existence. Therefore, the instrumentarian
power configures a real democratic threat by continuously renewing capitalism's grip on society's
learning division, leading to a constant erosion of our freedom (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 389).
For this reason, the concern about the consolidation of Big Techs' monopolies is in the
political as well as the economic sphere, given that technology giants threaten the ideal of a
democracy whose power is distributed and decentralized (PETIT, 2020, p. 6). Therefore, without
a doubt, Big Techs have real influence over the economy, politics, and the most aggravating, the
individual, since their power is instrumentalized in order to conduct the users’ behavior in their
favor. In a way that the structuring of a new type of commerce is observed and relies on interference
in the waiting of the personality by means of behavioral modification, from which it remakes human
nature in the name of the certainty of profit.
21
4. COMPETITION REGULATION IN THE INFORMATIONAL ECONOMY
Once established the premises of the Big Techs’ monopoly power in the digital economy, it is
essential to analyze the impacts resulting from this dominance and seek solutions that restore users'
autonomy over their data, restore democracy, and foster a market composed of fair competition.
Although the antitrust enforcement focused on innovation increased since late 20th century,
evidenced by the 1995 federal guidelines on intellectual property licensing (KOVACIC; SHAPIRO, 2000,
p. 57), in the case of Big Techs, it is possible to observe that these companies command the market,
each in their respective field, while competing only among themselves.
At first, technology companies’ invasions of privacy were allegedly fueled by the absence
of specific legislation – both data protection and antitrust – that placed limits on the advance of
platforms, in addition to the alleged reciprocal interest of technology companies and government
intelligence in abusive surveillance practices (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 31). However, as the social, economic,
political consequences of technological monopolies became more evident and recurrent, the need
for a more active state intervention was realized.
From this perspective, the monopoly of Big Techs treats personal data way more aggressively
than in a scenario where there would be a solid market competition and competitiveness, to the
point that their domination over the market not only consolidates their economic power, but also
defaces privacy (US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 40). This is a relevant discussion “as existing
antitrust laws must remain the primary rules for the protection of market competition and no radical
reform is needed” (PETIT, 2020, p. 7).
In this context, it is noted that competition regulation, especially in the digital markets, plays
a very important role as a mechanism for preserving privacy and protecting personal data. In fact,
the same way Glaeser and Shleifer (2003, p. 403) pointed out that regulation emerge “as a political
response to the failure of private litigation to keep up with the community idea of justice, Regulation
can also be seen as a political response to the market's inability to self-regulate fairly and eectively,
aiming at the community's well-being, serving as a mechanism designed to promote the community's
interest and ensure that principles of equity are preserved.
Thus, it becomes evident that competition regulation, particularly in digital markets,
assumes a critical role in safeguarding both privacy and personal data. As a matter of fact, it should
be emphasized that – while the scenario with insucient competition alone may lead to reduced
product quality in many markets – this loss due to monopolization is even more pronounced in
digital markets and in turn damaging to privacy and data protection, since product quality in digital
media is oten itself the relevant locus of competition. Therefore, “without transparency or eective
choice, dominant firms may impose terms of service with weak privacy protections that are designed
to restrict consumer choice” (US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 42).
A concrete example of the statement was the controversial update of WhatsApp's Terms
of Use and Privacy Policy in Brazil, announced in early 2021. In light of this episode, Telegram –
WhatsApp's biggest “competitor” communication platform – had in August of that year a peak in
downloads, reaching the 1 billion users’ mark (ROSA, 2021). It should be noted, however, that despite
the uproar involving the referred controversy, just in a matter of a few days, everyone went back and
continued using the application normally, as such permeate as the main means of communication
22
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
of Brazilians. Notwithstanding the weak privacy policy – widely known by the society – a few months
later WhatsApp announced a new tool to users, enabling payments and transfers through the app, the
“WhatsApp Pay” (INSTITUTO MILLENIUM, 2021). The new tool was easily introduced, even in the face
of the security instability regarding data protection by the platform, serving as an example of how a
monopolistic company can put users at risk, and still remain in control.
The dominance of Big Techs over certain segments, such as the case of WhatsApp – coupled
with the lack of a real competitor – weakens privacy and data protection, and inevitably the user,
since the latter is held hostage to the determinations and impositions of this monopoly. Antitrust
laws have the potential to ensure fair competition among companies, and consequently provide data
subjects with more autonomy and power over their information. It is given that “if two firms in a
market are owned by the same people, those firms likely have less motivation to compete vigorously
than would two firms owned by dierent people” (SHAMBAUGH; NUNN; BREITWISER; LIU, 2018, p. 12).
Fundamentally, Competition Law – understood in its true sense as a means of structural
combat to power situations – as a way to guide and transform the operation of markets, exactly
by fighting dominant economic power, since, above all, fighting economic power and its abusive
exercise is nothing more than fighting the excluding individualism in market relations (SALOMÃO
FILHO, 2021, p. xi). As seen, beyond the technological development itself, the real merit behind the
rise of technological giants is in the deep relations established between companies and users, which
began with “its disregard for the boundaries of private human experience and the moral integrity of
the autonomous individual” (ZUBOFF, 2019, p. 24).
Among the several ways that one can endure to suppress competitors in a specific market
segment, the “buy-or-bury” illegal practice stands out as a “common” tactic employed by the tech
giants to maintain their dominance, especially ater numerous failed attempts to develop innovative
features, as occurred with the social networking giant Meta, formerly known as Facebook (FTC…, 2021,
para. 1). In advance, it is important to remember that Facebook is still a social network with a user base
of over two billion people – and alone has control over 80% of the time the average user spends using
social media – making the platform one of the most powerful method of personal discourse, which is
a clear reflection of its monopoly power in the social media segment and evokes the sense that others
social networks with fewer users don’t even have a chance to compete (SRINIVASAN, 2019, p. 45).
It is in this precisely context that Meta had acquest two of its biggest rivals: Instagram, in 2012,
and WhatsApp, in 2014. Notwithstanding the company's attempt to deny its monopoly and its anti-
competitive practices, it is a fact that Meta, since its founding, has acquired over 90 companies, most
of which were startups and while on the surface many of these mergers may have – at least appeared
to have – positive economic benefits, they inevitably provide a strategic means for dominant firms
to solidify and protect their dominance (GLICK; RUETSCHLIN, 2019, p. 4). This underscores the fact
that the company consolidated its monopoly, severely by hampering the ability of its competitors to
even exist in the same segment. Such a fact that aligned with the purchase of the small innovative
companies that have the potential to eventually become a competitor, Meta has vitiated the entire
competitive process, annihilated competition and limiting consumer choice (FTC…, 2021, para. 5).
Therefore, the concern regarding the containment of monopolies and their role in protecting
privacy and personal data protection is evident. However, it is necessary to keep in mind that
competition regulation by itself is not capable of promoting privacy and personal data protection,
23
since market competitiveness alone is not capable of ensuring that Big Techs develop a commitment
to care about the treatment of users’ personal information (PETIT, 2020, p. 246). Nevertheless, it
doesn’t mean that the antitrust laws don’t have significant value in addressing the privacy and data
protection issue as part of its regulation – as does by tackling monopolies – particularly given that
“entrenched power of firms with weak privacy protections has created a kill zone around the market
for products that enhance privacy online” (US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, 2022, p. 37).
Competition regulations targeted at digital markets are being increasingly discussed and
implemented worldwide. The DMA designed by the European Union serves as a prime example of such
regulation. The DMA identifies gatekeepers who oer core platform services and possess significant
economic power (EUROPEAN UNION, 2022, p. 2). This novel instrument departs from conventional
measures of market intervention, as it considers not only a company’s dominance in the market
but also its qualitative characteristics and the services oered. As well explained by Forgioni (2022,
p. 188) “the European Union sees the opening, the possibility of access, the competition and the
competitiveness structure of the market as mechanisms capable of promoting economic welfare,
competitivity and integration of the markets in its territory”.
The development of competition regulation in digital markets directly reflects on privacy
and data protection enforcement, as it strives to restrain the dominance of Big Tech companies and
underscores the state's willingness to interfere with market structures whenever necessary to ensure
competitiveness (SALOMÃO FILHO, 2021, p. 28). In fact, the regulation of Digital Markets
would not only promote an increase of sales through smaller platforms but would
also impact positively the market growth. It would strengthen condence in the
platform business environment. The benets expected would enhance the potential
of innovation amongst smaller businesses as well as improving the quality of service
and therefore the consumer welfare. Once implemented, the foreseen interventions
would reduce competitive asymmetries between gatekeepers and other platforms
(BAGNOLI, 2021, p. 150).
According to Recital 36 of the DMA, Big Techs – classified as Gatekeepers – possess an advantage
resulting from the personal data treatment for online advertising purposes. This advantage creates
a barrier to entry for smaller players, who will struggle to accumulate similar amounts of data. To
prevent any undermining of competition, Gatekeepers “should enable end-users to freely choose to
opt-in to such data processing and sign-in practices by oering a less personalized but equivalent
alternative, and without making the use of the core platform service or certain functionalities thereof
conditional upon the end-user's consent” (EUROPEAN UNION, 2022, p. 9).
At last, while competition regulations cannot guarantee privacy and personal data protection,
they are essential to turning down the Big Tech’s dominant power and promoting a more competitive
market. The DMA is an example that by restraining the dominance of Big Tech and reducing competitive
asymmetries between gatekeepers and other platforms, ultimately benefiting the market growth,
innovation and consumer welfare, as well as privacy and users’ personal data protection.
24
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
CONCLUSION
The rise of the Informational Economy and the dominance of Big Tech companies in digital
markets have brought privacy and data protection to the forefront of consumer and regulatory
concerns. As the importance of personal data continues to grow, there is a pressing need for new
regulatory approaches to address the complex challenges posed by the digital era.
This article has explored how competition regulation can be used as a mechanism to protect
privacy and data protection in the digital markets. To this purpose, it was demonstrated how the
transformation of the economy with the rise of digital technologies happened, characterized by the
increasing importance of data as a strategic asset, and the emergence of digital markets domination
power by Big Tech companies. Aterwards was addressed the intersection between competition
and data privacy concerns, focusing on the practice of behavioral profiling and the misuse of the
“instrumentarian power”.
To address these concerns, it was shown that competition regulation can play a vital role
in protecting privacy and data protection in the digital markets, by promoting competitiveness and
preventing anti-competitive behavior by dominant players. As such, competition law can help to
create an environment where eective competitivity exists and motivates better standards for privacy
and data protection between competitors’ companies. As a case in point, the DMA of the European
Union was chosen as a reference of how competition regulation can be used to address these issues.
Hence, the DMA seeks to establish rules for large online platforms that have significant market
power, imposing obligations related to data access and portability, and requiring transparency in
data practices. By integrating privacy and data protection concerns into competition policy, the DMA
represents a significant step towards creating a more sustainable and equitable digital economy,
without overriding the already specific existing regulations addressing privacy and data protection,
like the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR).
Moreover, regulatory authorities can also play a role in promoting competition in the
digital markets by enforcing antitrust laws and preventing dominant players from engaging in anti-
competitive practices, such as abusing their market power or engaging in exclusionary conduct. By
promoting competition, regulators can also help to reduce the risks associated with concentrated
market power, including the potential for abuse of personal data.
Overall, this article provides insights into the complex relationship between competition
regulation and privacy and data protection, highlighting the importance of a multidisciplinary
approach to addressing these critical issues in the digital era. As the digital economy continues to
evolve, it is essential that we continue to engage in robust discussions and collaborations to develop
eective and balanced regulatory frameworks that prioritize privacy and data protection while also
promoting competition and innovation.
REFERENCES
BAGNOLI, Vicente. Designing competition policy in digital markets for developing economies: how
the EU can contribute with the digital markets act and Digital Services Act. Revista de Defesa da
Concorrência, Brasília, v. 9, n. 2, p. 133-158, 2021. DOI: 10.52896/rdc.v9i2.957. Available at: https://bit.
25
ly/49oDitw. Accessed on: 19 fev. 2023.
BENKLER, Yochai. The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom.
New Haven: Yale University Press, 2006.
BIONI, Bruno Ricardo. Proteção de Dados Pessoais: a função e os limites do consentimento. Rio de
Janeiro: Forense, 2019.
CASTELLS, Manuel. The Internet Galaxy: Reflections on the Internet, Business, and Society. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2001.
DIAS, Patricia Yurie. Regulação da Internet como Administração da Privacidade. Journal of Law and
Regulation, Brasília, v. 3, n. 1, p. 239-254, 2017. Available at: https://bit.ly/3Mvq5VL. Accessed on: 1 dez.
2021.
DONEDA, Danilo Cesar Maganhoto. Da privacidade à proteção de dados pessoais: elementos da
formação da Lei Geral de Proteção de Dados. 2. ed. São Paulo: Thomson Reuters Brasil, 2020.
EUROPEAN UNION. Regulation (EU) 2022/1925 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14
September 2022 on contestable and fair markets in the digital sector and amending Directives (EU)
2019/1937 and (EU) 2020/1828 (Digital Markets Act). Ofcial Journal of the European Union, Bruxelas, v.
65, n. L 317, p. 1-62, 2022. Available at: https://bit.ly/40ptWt3. Accessed on: 22 Jan. 2023.
FOER, Franklin. World without mind: the existential threat of Big Tech. New York: Penguin Press, 2017.
FORGIONI, Paula A. Os fundamentos do Antitruste. 12. ed. rev. atual. São Paulo: Thomson Reuters
Brasil, 2022
FTC alleges Facebook resorted to illegal buy-or-bury scheme to crush competition ater string of failed
attempts to innovate. Federal Trade Commission, Washington, 19 ago. 2021. Available at: https://bit.
ly/3Qok6TN. Accessed on: 10 mar. 2023.
GLAESER, Edward, L.; SHLEIFER, Andrei. The Rise of the Regulatory State. Journal of Economic Literature,
Pittsburgh, v. 41, n. 2, p. 401-425. 2003. Available at: https://bit.ly/3tZkssB. Accessed on: 22 oct. 2023
GLICK, Mark; RUETSCHLIN, Catherine. Big Tech Acquisitions and the Potential Competition Doctrine:
The case of Facebook. New York: Institute for New Economic Thinking, 2019. (Working Paper Series,
104). Available at: https://bit.ly/3u2rCfF. Accessed on: 3 dez. 2021.
INSTITUTO MILLENIUM. Entenda como funciona o WhatsApp Pay. Revista Exame. [S. l.], 29 jul. 2021.
Available at: https://bit.ly/463GCam. Accessed on: 03 dez. 2021.
KHAN, Lina M. Amazon's Antitrust Paradox. The Yale Law Journal, New Haven, v. 126, p. 710-805, 2017.
Available at: https://bit.ly/3xtFiQr. Accessed on: 14 mar. 2023.
KOURY, Suzy Elizabeth; OLIVEIRA, Lia Arrais. Novos Rumos do Direito da Concorrência: O Controle do
Monopólio e a Proteção ao Consumidor na Economia de Dados Pessoais com base na Lei 12.529/2011.
Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v. 10, n. 1, p. 87-108, 2022. Available at: https://bit.
ly/47in1UV. Accessed on: 21 fev. 2023.
KOVACIC, William E.; SHAPIRO, Carl. Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking. The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Pittsburgh, v. 14, n. 1, p. 43–60, 2000. Available at: http://www.jstor.
26
CAVALLARO, Amanda de Castro. Big Techs, data protection, and competition regulation in a data-
driven economy: a multidisciplinary approach. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v.
11, n. 2, p. 11-26, 2023.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v11i2.1044
org/stable/2647050. Accessed on: 22 Oct. 2023.
KSHETRI, Nir. COVID-19 Meets Big Tech. Computer, [S. l.], v. 53, n. 8, p. 10-13, 2020. Available at: http://
dx.doi.org/10.1109/mc.2020.2996698. Accessed at: 22 oct. 2023.
LANCIERI, Filippo Maria; SAKOWSKI, Patrícia Alessandra Morita. Concorrência em mercados digitais:
uma revisão dos relatórios especializados: Documento de Trabalho n° 005/2020. Brasília: Conselho
Administrativo de Defesa Econômica, 2020. Disponível em: https://bit.ly/40lnkMz. Accessed on: 27 jan.
2023.
LYON, David. Surveillance After September 11: Themes for the 21st Century. Malden, MA: Polity, 2003.
MOROZOV, Evgeny. Big Tech: a ascensão dos dados e a morte da política. Tradução por Claudio
Marcondes. São Paulo: Ubu, 2018.
NYBO, Erik Fontenele. O Poder dos Algoritmos. São Paulo: Enlaw, 2019.
PETIT, Nicolas. Big Tech & the Digital Economy: The Moligopoly Scanerio. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 2020.
ROSA, Giovanni Santa. Telegram atinge 1 bilhão de downloads após polêmica na política do WhatsApp.
Tecnoblog, Americana, 31 ago. 2021. Available at: https://bit.ly/3QpTm5f. Accessed on: 3 dez. 2021.
SALOMÃO FILHO, Calixto. Direito Concorrencial. 2. ed. Rio de Janeiro: Forense, 2021.
SHAMBAUGH, Jay; NUNN, Ryan; BREITWISER, Audrey; LIU, Patrick. The State of Competition and
Dynamism: Facts about Concentration, Start-ups, and Related Policies. Washington: Brookings
Institute, 2018. Available at: https://bit.ly/3QGSJ8X. Accessed on: 21 nov. 2021
SHELANSKI, Howard A. Information, innovation, and competition policy for the internet. University
of Pennsylvania Law Review, Pennsylvania, v. 161, n. 6, p. 1701-1732, 2013. Available at: https://bit.
ly/3MujoDh. Access in: 22 jan 2023
SRINIVASAN, Dina. The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A monopolist’s Journey Towards Pervaise
Surveillance in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy. Berkeley Business Law Journal, Berkeley,
v. 16, n. 1, 2019. Available at: https://bit.ly/46URxEt. Accessed on: 27 dez. 2022
THE GREAT Hack. Direção de Karim Amer e Jehane Noujaim. Estados Unidos: Netflix, 2019. 1 vídeo (114
min). Available at: https://www.netflix.com/title/80117542. Accessed on: 15 mar. 2023.
US HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES. Investigation of Competition in Digital Markets. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Oce, 2022. Available at: https://bit.ly/3SnznXx. Accessed on: 13 mar. 2023
U. S. SUPREME COURT. Louis K. Liggett v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517 (1933). Washington: U. S. Supreme Court,
1933. Available at: https://supreme.justia.com/cases/federal/us/288/517/. Accessed on: 15 fev. 2023.
WYLIE, Christopher. Mindf*ck: Cambridge Analytica and the Plot to Break America. New York: Random
House, 2019.
ZUBOFF, Shoshana. The Age of Surveillance Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at the New
Frontier of Power. New York: PublicAairs, 2019.