
98
LYRA, Marcos Puccioni de Oliveira; PIRES-ALVES, Camila Cabral. Innovation Concerns in horizontal
mergers: empirical evidence from Brazilian Merger Control. Revista de Defesa da Concorrência,
Brasília, v. 13, n. 1, p. 95-109, 2025.
https://doi.org/10.52896/rdc.v13i1.1927
Innovation concerns play a dual role in merger analysis. First, it may influence the assessment
of mergers conducted under the standard analysis. When merging firms compete in a product market,
innovation may aect how mergers impact prices, quality, entry barriers, among other factors. Second,
innovation becomes the central concern when the merger aects an innovation market - requiring an
innovation-specific assessment, which we will discuss further below.
The standard analysis of horizontal mergers focuses on competition within a relevant product
market, typically defined through the Hypothetical Monopolist Test (HMT)
7
. In the assessment of
competitive significance stage, authorities consider market shares and concentration indices, such as
the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)
8
, as proxies for market power. However, in markets with highly
dierentiated
9
or innovative products, these structural indicators lose explanatory power. Regarding
the latter, it is important to notice that the relationship between market concentration and innovation
remains inconclusive in the literature
10
. Both the US and European HMGs acknowledge this complexity
and advise caution when interpreting concentration metrics in innovation-driven markets (DOJ; FTC,
2010, p. 16-17; European Commission, 2004, p. 6).
The next step, assessing unilateral eects, examines a firm’s increased ability to exercise
market power post-merger. While price eects dominate this analysis, innovation may also be aected.
For instance, innovation-intensive industries oten have high entry barriers (such as Research and
Development - R&D - investment), and there may be rivalry more on innovation than price (European
Commission, 2004, p. 12; Cade, 2016a, p. 27). The US HMG explicitly discusses unilateral innovation
eects (DOJ; FTC, 2010).
In this paper, we define negative innovation eects as reductions in incentives to innovate
post-merger - whether by the merged entity or its rivals.
11
According to Kokkoris and Valletti (2020),
these eects may take two forms: (i) decreased incentives to continue ongoing innovation eorts,
possibly delaying and/or interrupting these eorts and (ii) reduced incentives to initiate new
innovation, resulting in less innovation in the future
12
.
7 The Hypothetical Monopolist Test (HMT) checks whether a hypothetical monopolist could profitably apply a small
but significant non-transitory increase in price (SSNIP). If such an increase is profitable, the market is well-defined; otherwise,
the test is remade adding other products or geographic areas to the hypothetical monopolist until the price increase becomes
profitable (DOJ; FTC, 2010, p. 7-15)
8 The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index is calculated by summing the squared markets shares of all firms in the product
market and used as an indicative of the level of concentration in that product market.
9 With homogenous products, there is a direct relation in the Cournot model between market power and the HHI which
supports the screening role of structural variables. With dierentiated products, factors like cross elasticity of demand and
diversion ratios - defined as a fraction of sales diverted to another producer due to a price increase (DOJ; FTC, 2010, p. 21) - play
a role in determining substitutability between the products of merging parties (Cade, 2016a, p. 36-37).
10 The well-known Arrow-Schumpeter controversy indicates two dierent positions on the relation between structure
and innovation, as Arrow (1962) presents a model which indicates that competitive firms have higher incentives to engage in
innovation eorts to escape competition than monopolists, while Schumpeter (1942) emphasizes that larger firms would be
more likely to innovate. This debate has both theoretical and empirical work, but the latter did not provide a definitive answer
to this debate.
11 Another way of assessing harm to innovation is the through the elimination of parallel research eorts, the Diversity
Argument, connected to the evolutionary approach (Jorde; Teece, 1990; Farrell, 2006; Sidak and Teece, 2009). A greater number
of innovation eorts increases the probability of at least one getting to the market, allowing a better functioning of the role of
the market as a selector of innovation and, as Farrell (2006) states, a diversity of approaches is beneficial in itself.
12 These channels are similar to the unilateral innovation eects present in the 2010 US Horizontal Merger Guidelines, as
the HMG includes a subsection dedicated to innovation in the unilateral eects section, mentioning two channels of innovation
eects: (i) if a merging party is engaging in innovation eorts that could divert sales from the other, and (ii) when firms have
similar innovation capabilities, which could capture sales from each other, resulting in longer-term innovation harm (DOJ; FTC,