1110
LINHARES, Athayde Amanda; ROS, Luiz Guilherme. The midlife crisis of the antitrust goals:
where does the Brazilian Competition Authority stand among Harvard, Chicago and Neo-
Brandesianists? Revista de Defesa da Concorrência, Brasília, v. 10, n. 2, p. 7-23, 2022.
https://doi.org/10.5286/rdc.v10i2.987
Canadian and called Competition Act (1885).
5
In turn, the development of competition law – as well as
the broad reach this eld of study has attained – has occurred in the United States. The beginning of
the discussion regarding this eld of study dates to 1877, when a strike movement started by railroad
employees in the State of West Virginia spread throughout North America and resulted in a massive
blockage of transport, causing a signicant shortage of goods in the main urban centers.
This movement, which spread to several economic sectors, had the support of several
public authorities, as well as private agents, taking on signicant proportions in the North American
economy and political system. At the time, the main dissatisfaction was related to the power amassed
by large conglomerates (trusts)
6
and, consequently, the way in which such private agents were able
to inuence the political-economic scenario, asserting their interests at any cost.
7
For no other reason trusts and antitrust law (a nomenclature that derives from that name)
were at the center of the debates during the presidential election in the United States of America,
with the repudiation of trusts and the promise to ght them being a common point among candidates
(FERRAZ, 2014). Finally, to stop these conglomerates and their harmful effects on the market and
consumers, the Sherman Act (1890)
8
emerged and was later complemented by the Clayton Act (1914)
and the FTC Act (1914).
9
The Brazilian author Calixto Salomão
10
claims that the emergence of the Sherman Act would
be related to consumer protection. On the other hand, Paula Forgioni,
11
also Brazilian, argues that
the legislation would have been drafted with the purpose of protecting the market itself, which was
self-destructive given the excess of economic freedom and lack of control by authorities. Lina Khan
12
,
current president of the Federal Trade Commission, mentions that the purpose of the Law would be
to preserve “open markets”, as well as increase opportunities for new entrants, thus preventing large
corporations from extracting wealth from consumers and producers, and, consequently, market
concentration and abuse.
5 Canada is credited with pioneering competition law in 1889, by enacting the Act for the prevention and suppression
of combinations formed in restraint of trade, whose purpose was to combat arrangements or combinations aimed at restricting
trade by xing prices or restriction of production (cartels), which was incorporated three years later into Canada’s rst Criminal
Code. In this legislation it was made explicit that the xing of prices and other agreements between competitors were species
of abusive conduct (GABAN; DOMINGUES, 2009, p. 4).
6 U.S. antitrust was born in 1890 out of a concern for the power and exploitations of the new, large, and powerful
business organizations called trusts (FOX, 2013, p. 1).
7 Characteristic of this position is the cartoon shown by Schapiro (2018, p. 715). According to the drawing, trusts were
seen as the “bosses” of the senators and, consequently, the most important political agents in the North American scenario.
8 For further information about elements that inuenced the original version of the Sherman Act, see Diniz (2018).
9 Not since 1912, when Teddy Roosevelt ran for President emphasizing the need to control corporate power, have
antitrust issues had such political salience. While Roosevelt did not win, Congress passed the Federal Trade Commission Act
and the Clayton Act in 1914, signicantly strengthening the Sherman Act. (SCHAPIRO, 2018, p. 715).
10 The exposition of the political-economic factors relevant to the approval of the Sherman Act makes it possible to
correctly outline the issue. First, it is quite evident that the biggest concern with monopolies at that time was their negative
economic effects on the consumer (SALOMÃO FILHO, 2007, p. 71).
11 Indeed, this legislation should be understood as the most signicant legal document to showcase the reaction
against the concentration of power in the hands of a few economic agents, and seek to regulate it. It should not be said
that the Sherman Act constitutes a reaction against economic liberalism, as it aimed precisely at correcting distortions that
were brought about by excessive capital accumulation, that is, correcting the distortions created by the liberal system itself.
Despite the contrary opinion of part of the North American literature, the Sherman Act tried, at rst, to protect the market (or
the productive system) against its self-destructive effects (FORGIONI, 2012, p. 65).
12 Taken as a whole, the antitrust laws were intended to preserve open markets and enhance opportunity, prevent
large rms from extracting wealth from producers and consumers, and safeguard against extreme concentrations of private
power (KHAN, 2018, p. 7).